Case
study 4
1. INTRODUCTION
Over four and a
half decades of its existence
socialist Yugoslavia has amended
four constitutions.1 This very fact
indicated the problems and
challenges the Yugoslav federation
had been faced with continually
since its establishment.2 Responses
to existing circumstances, domestic
and international, were being
searched for in different
constitutional solutions that were
also used as guideposts to new modes
of functioning of Yugoslav
political, economic and social
system. The same as the first two –
proclaimed in 1946 and 1953 – that,
due to specific situations the
country found itself in (the end of
the war and the (Communist
Information Bureau) Comintern
Resolution), placed the ongoing
political developments in the
forefront and were, as Vladimir
Bakarić put it, more “concerned with
the past,”3 not even the third
Constitution of 1963 managed to
respond to the challenges facing the
Yugoslav federation. Though passed
in by far more stable political
situation than its predecessors,
this Constitution was declared
against the turbulent economic and
political backdrop of the late 1950s
and early 1960s. But that was the
time when the Yugoslav “economic
wonder” of the country’s
development, society’s modernization
and growing standards of living was
slowly losing momentum. Heavier and
heavier burden of economic problems
pressing the country resulted in a
Pandora’s Box: other problems that
had been placed in the back seat in
the previous period due to economic
growth emerged. In early 1974
socialist Yugoslavia got its fourth
Constitution. By its contents, and
consequences as well, this was
probably the most complex project
for defining internal relations in
the Yugoslav federation. It has to
be stressed, however, that
constitutional provisions voted in
on February 21, 1974 by the Federal
Assembly had been backed with
years-long exchanges, mutual
adjustments and negotiations.
Despite the proclaimed agreement in
stances, the said process had
frequently revealed radically
different views development of
Yugoslavia and its socialism.
Inter-republican and interethnic
relations, the role of the federal
center and the future of
self-government at all levels and in
all segments of the society were
just some of the issues reflecting
the controversy of the debate on
constitutional reform. Declaration
of the Constitution did not put an
end to these disputes and
antagonisms. And in the last decade
of socialist Yugoslavia’s existence,
this very Constitution will stand
for a legal starting point in the
country’s disintegration.
2. SELF-GOVERNMENT AND
(DE)CENTRALIZATION
The role assigned
to (central) government or, to put
it more precisely its power, was
among main characteristics of and at
the same time a specific difference
between Yugoslav and Soviet models
of socialism-building. Following the
Cominform Resolution Yugoslav
communists opted for a
sociopolitical experiment meant to
prove their distancing from
Stalinist understanding of Marx’s
and Engels’ ideas of a state’s
“dying out.” Accordingly, the state
should be deprived of power – as
soon and as much as possible – and
the concept of workers’ and social
self-government should be the means
for attaining that goal.4 However,
the said concept did not imply that
just the federal center should be
made weaker. A radical
decentralization should equally
weaken and then eliminate the
predominance of the federation, but
republican centers of power as well.
On the other hand, local
self-governments and direct
producers – i.e. workers via their
workers’ councils – should be key
players in political and economic
development of the society. What
happened in real life was quite
contrary to this idea
notwithstanding all the proclaimed
principles. In fear of economic
anarchy, powers in (planning)
economy remained invested in the
federation.5 The biggest losers of
this policy were republics. The
emphasis placed on social and
workers’ self-government at lowest
levels, and the political
leadership’s stance that national
issues had been settled (in the war,
i.e. revolution) did not encourage
development of Yugoslav federalism
but, on the contrary, strengthened
centralistic tendencies. Annulment
of the Chamber of Peoples in the
federal assembly also testified that
decentralization, in the form of
self-government, was carried out at
the detriment of federalism. Under
constitutional provisions of 1946
the Assembly of the Federal People’s
Republic of Yugoslavia had two
chambers – the Federal Chamber and
the Chamber of Peoples – the latter
composed of representatives of all
republics and provinces. This
provision was amended in the
Constitutional Law of 1953: the
Chamber of Peoples was replaced by
the Chamber of Producers.6
In the late 1950s
the country’s stabilized
international standing, growing
economic prosperity but also many
half-finished solutions in the
self-government system gave rise to
first debates on functioning of the
Yugoslav federal model. Dušan
Bilandžić takes that the issue was
firstly placed on the agenda in
1958, on February 6, at the “secret”
meeting assembling members of the
Executive Committee of the Central
Committee of the League of
Communists of Yugoslavia and top
brass of republican and federal
institutions.7 The strike staged by
miners in Trbovlje, the first bigger
expression of the working class’
dissatisfaction after the end of
World War II, triggered off a deeper
analysis of Yugoslavia’s
sociopolitical situation. The
analysis was mostly focused on the
relationship between republics and
the federation, and relations
between the republics but on
interethnic relations as well.
Despite worrisome theses voiced
throughout the debate, the party
leadership decided to pursue along
the same course of social
development. Thus the problems were
not overcome but, moreover, under
the new circumstances marked by
negative influence of the economy,
became factors of instability that
weighted on Yugoslavia until its
disintegration. To put it simply,
the basic problem boiled down to the
calculation of the amounts of “who”
was giving to the federation and
“who” getting from it. Republics
established as socialist but also
nation-states added a new dimension
to the antagonism between developed
and underdeveloped regions,
inherited from the Kingdom of
Yugoslavia. One of major goal of
centralized economic and investment
policy was to decrease the existing
disproportion. As long as economic
growth was high everyone was happy
with this policy. The underdeveloped
were being paid huge sums from the
common treasury to develop their
economic resources and social
standard, whereas the developed
benefited from their better starting
point in industrialization,
infrastructure and common market
opportunities, as well as lower
prices they paid for raw material.8
Disagreements between supporters of
the centralized planned economy and
advocates of decentralization on the
principles of self-government were
evident throughout the 1950s. At
this early stage the resistance to
centralism did not automatically
imply advocacy for more rights to be
invested in republics. This was
probably best illustrated in the
stances of Vladimir Bakarić, the
number one of Croatian communist
and, together with Edvard Kardelj,
strong advocate for economic and
political decentralization. In his
view, the self-government reform
should have proportionally decreased
the powers of federal and republican
institutions. Stronger republican
statehood (including Croatia’s) is
the expression of nationalism, he
said, and contrary to interests of
the (Croatian) people.9 Advocates of
decentralization argued that the
struggle against centralism and
planned economy was in the interest
of all citizens of Yugoslavia rather
than just one people or republic.
However, economic growth of the
developed slowed down for the
benefit of the underdeveloped was
also not in the interest of the
entire socialist community. And this
exactly became a crucial economic
and political problem in the
functioning of the Yugoslav
federation. “Developed regions,
those that made bigger progress,
must be lagging in the domain of
investment; otherwise, those that
are not made progress cannot develop
themselves,” he said in 1960, adding
that due to such policy Croatia had
been lagging behind less developed
republics for the past 15 years.10 In
Bakarić’s opinion – to be accepted
by the majority of the Croatian
leadership – the federation should
become much more flexible (to
different solutions), i.e. it should
“flex.”11 Motives of the opponents of
decentralization were different. For
some, loss of the monopoly on
centralistic decision-making led
towards nationalism and
disintegration; as for
representatives of less developed
republics, this was all more about
existential than ideological issue.
They saw liberalization of the
economic policy, introduction of
market criteria in economic life
and, above all, the end of federal
subventions as insurmountable
obstacles to further development of
their societies. All this once again
revealed many lose ends of the
Yugoslav sociopolitical experiment.
Along with the existing
argumentation relations between
republics and interethnic relations
became main criteria for
decision-making throughout the
1960s.
3. FLEXING THE FEDERATION
High – or, to put
it precisely, unrealistic –
expectations from the country’s
economic growth, along with
growingly evident shortcomings of
the existing system, brought about
(another) crisis in the early 1960s.
Deeper and deeper gap between theory
and practice of the Yugoslav system
of self-government remained a key
problem. Full implementation of
provisions of federal legislation
and wordings of party documents was
impossible “in the field.” The state
remained the most powerful subject
of economic policy. The attempt at a
mini-reform in 1961 failed. True,
for the first time since 1950 the
state permitted enterprises to
independently decide on the use of
their income – but that was mostly
the one and only achievement.12
According to
Branko Horvat, one of most renowned
Yugoslav economist of the time, the
reformist attempt failed for two
reasons. Firstly, political
opposition to further liberalization
of the economy (and society) was
growing. Secondly, nothing or almost
nothing was known about functioning
of a decentralized economy
mechanisms, which was why the reform
was neither properly prepared nor
implemented.13 After ten years of
permanent economic growth the new
crisis baffled many and even shaken
their belief. Doubts about the
rationale behind decentralization
and more radical function of market
mechanisms were more and more given
voice to. The dilemma – to stick to
the reformist course or resume the
old model – split economist and
Yugoslavia’s political leadership
alike. By their views on the role a
state should play in development of
a society, their split boiled down
to two camps: centralists and
decentralists. The former were also
labeled conservatives, bureaucrats
and dogmatists, while the latter –
liberals.14 As the time went by, this
heterogeneity was more and more
manifest. Antagonisms between
republics, peoples and generations
just fit in the existing ones.
Although opposing stands were more
and more evident it was hard to tell
at the beginning which of the two
opposing “camps” individual leaders
have belonged to.
The situation
culminated in 1962. In his opening
address to the session of the
Executive Committee of the CC of the
LCY on March 14-16, 1962, Tito said,
“In my opinion, this is not an
economic but a political crisis that
shakes our country…Just take a look,
comrades, at the atmosphere of the
meetings of the Federal Executive
Council!...Listen to the sound and
contents of the debates they engaged
in!...One often asks himself, ‘Well,
is that country of ours really
capable of holding on, not to
disintegrate?’”15 Quoting major
reasons behind the crisis Tito spoke
as a mouthpiece of the conservative
current. “What we are having now is
unconcern, party indiscipline,
cadres who are swept by the
avalanche of petty bourgeois, under
the influence of nationalistic and
chauvinistic circles, and
preoccupied with everyday work and
local interests while neglecting
basic interests of our whole
community. And, of course, we also
have disparities in economic
development and unfair competing in
investments, construction of various
uneconomic and other not exactly
necessary facilities that are costly
and insufficient solidarity among
the republics.”16 Speaking of
decentralization Yugoslavia’s Number
One concludes, “Some of our people
are more and more perceiving in
decentralization the character and
sense of disintegration.17 The same,
conservative tone marks one of
Tito’s best known speeches,
delivered in Split on May 6, 1962.18
Differences in
views about Yugoslavia’s future were
also bigger and bigger among
economic experts. Open conflicts
between them coincided with
conflicts in the political
leadership. Key issue debated at the
conference of the Alliance of
Economists of Yugoslavia, in
December 1962 in Belgrade, was
whether to prioritize market economy
or (social) planned. A month later
in Zagreb (January 17-19, 1963) an
even sharper discussion by same
participants ensued. This time the
opposing groupings presented two
documents (known as Yellow and White
Book) whereby each argued for its
economic models.19 The “Yellow Book”
composed in the Federal Bureau of
Planning, indentified the causes of
the crisis in poorly prepared and
implemented “liberal” reforms
(1961), and serious mistakes made in
the structure of investment. The
“White Book” was produced in Zagreb
at the initiative of Vladimir
Bakarić. Its authors were Croatia’s
leading economists, including Savka
Dabčević Kučar, Jakov Sirotković and
Ivo Perišin who would play more and
more important roles in the next
period. According to the three,
centralistic planning was useful in
the early stage of economic
development, but then became
extremely dysfunctional. Now, when
economic growth was at a much higher
level, the economy should function
more by market laws, and less by
interventions of “planners” or
politicians. Dennison Rusinow takes
that the “White Book” was the first
comprehensive document that signaled
the Croatian model for a developed
socialist state.20
Although the
crisis shaking the country and
criticism of the economic policy by
Yugoslavia’s leading economists
played into the hands of
“centralists” that was not enough to
generate a U-turn in governance.
Like in many other similar
situations Josip Broz Tito had a
final say. Despite between-the-lines
wavering in his earlier speeches
throughout 1962, as early as in July
of the same year, at the Fourth
Plenary Session of the CC of the LCY
he made no bones about his idea of
Yugoslavia’s future course. Having
warned of the growing
bureaucratization, he criticized
dogmatic centralism and once again
emphasized the crucial role of
decentralization: decentralization
of the state capital in favor of
direct producers in the first place.21
The choice he made signaled victory
of reformist forces and the
possibility for further improvements
in the existing system. This was the
atmosphere in which the Constitution
of the SFRY – also called the
Self-government Charter – was
declared (April 7, 1963) and the 8th
Congress of the LCY (December 7-13,
1964) held.22 Adoption of the
self-government idea – and almost
fifteen years of its inconsequent
implementation – Yugoslavia’s
economic and hence overall social
development found themselves in a
blind alley. The level of
development the country has reached
called for more active involvement
in global economic processes and
excluded fragmentary measures
compromising by character.
A package of
measures the Federal Assembly
adopted on July 24, 1965, implying
the most radical transformation of
the country’s economic system since
the beginning of self-government in
1950, was expected to solve the
problem. The economic reform of 1965
took into account all the lessons
learnt and set several main goals.23
It posited that further development
was possible only by having the
extensive production model replaced
by an intensive production one.24 Some
new measures were introduced in
addition to those ensuring continued
struggle against still omnipresent
elements of bureaucratic
centralization and creating
conditions for enterprises to
directly dispose of segments of
their accumulation and increased
reproduction. With a view to making
Yugoslavia as good as possible
player at the international market,
prices underwent correction (they
grew in this case) and customs
changed accordingly. Dinar was
devaluated vis-à-vis US dollar as a
prelude to changes in the domain of
foreign trade.25 Probably Dennison
Rusinow best described how
all-inclusive and extensive the
economic reform was. In his report
on Yugoslavia he called it, in order
to make it better understandable to
American readers, „laissez-faire
socialism“or „Adam Smith without
private capitalism“.26
This time,
however, it became evident at the
very beginning of the reform that
desired results would be much harder
to achieve than expected. Standards
of living suffered first since
citizens’ expenditures grew by 35%
due to overall price raise. The
state intervened: only two weeks
after the reform had been started it
decided to put an end to price raise
of services and commodities.27 Then
the newly introduced earnings system
began generating by far bigger and
more far-reaching problems.
Autonomous status of enterprises
implied noninterference in business
policies on the one hand, but the
end of governmental subventions on
the other. Majority of enterprises
were not prepared for such a
“liberal” U-turn. Chain reaction of
negative effects on enterprises and
individuals alike ensued. In fear of
unfavorable business conditions
enterprises decided against cuts in
material expenses and wages; instead
they decided to stop employing
people and then to fire workers.
According to a November 1965 survey,
425 enterprises employing 225
thousand people had already given
walking papers to 12,574 and planned
to let go another 19,000.28 For the
first time after 1945 the number of
working people either stagnated or
decreased. Apart from numerical
indicators the said process also had
a strong influence on the structure
of the employed. More and more of
young and highly educated people
were among the unemployed: they soon
went abroad in search of jobs. Like
other trends in economy functioning,
GNP rate became negative. While in
1957-64 GNP rate was 10.2%, in 1964
– 65 it spiraled down to 2.9%. The
rate of industrial production from
12.5% dropped to 8%.29
Though many
reformist politicians were also
disappointed with the initial
outcomes it never occurred to them
to intervene in the proposed
measures. On the contrary, this time
they opted for a showdown with
“brakemen” of changes to manifest
how strongly they believed in the
reformist course. As mentioned
above, the term “conservatives” had
already embed itself in political
vocabulary to denote all the
opponents to the reforms. As the
time went by the term was implying
much more than that. In terms of
generations it mostly referred to
“old” partisan cadres and staunch
communists to whom economic and
political decentralization meant
nothing by disintegration of the
country they had created in the war.
From intellectual angle the term was
reserved for poorly educated or
uneducated persons in high offices
in the administration and economy
alike. They were aware that their
positions were shakier and shakier
with the country’s further
modernization and integration into
global economic processes.30 In
regional terms, conservatives were
practically equally distributed
throughout Yugoslavia although
undeveloped republics were usually
quoted as “centers” of their
operation. Generally speaking, the
new economic and social reform was
seen as more beneficial to Slovenia
and Croatia, whereas other (less
developed) republics would have made
more progress in a centralized
state. However, generalization by
the principle “liberal” and
reformist Slovenians and Croats on
the one hand, and conservative
Serbs, Macedonians, Montenegrins and
Muslims on the other only further
antagonized relations between
Yugoslav peoples. In their analyses
of the situation in Yugoslavia it
was in this perception that some
identified a generator of
misunderstanding and even growingly
open conflicts between republics.
“Serb ‘conservatives’ tend to think
that pro-reform ‘liberals’ are all
Croats and Slovenes, favoring the
interests of their relatively
developed parts of the country; at
the same time, a terrifying weakness
of Croat ‘liberals’ is their common
failure to perceive that all Serbs,
etc., are not necessarily
‘conservative’ representatives of
economically and politically
underdeveloped regions.“31 Considering
all this, it is obvious that
opponents to the reform did not make
up an organized and homogeneous
grouping, but it is evident as well
that they had a considerable
influence on the process of
decision-making and implementation
of the reform. It was clear,
therefore, that would be impossible
to choke down each individual
“conservative.” It was decided
instead to open fire just on the
very center of the resistance and a
person considered as the one
standing behind dogmatic, Unitarian
and anti-reformist trends. The
situation was the more so
complicated since this was about the
untouchable and omnipotent UDB
(Department of State Security) and
its boss Aleksandar Ranković
considered Yugoslavia’s number two
for years. His deposal following the
Fourth Plenary Session of the CC of
the LCY (July 1, 1966) and ensuing
reorganization of the state security
service initiated a wave of
liberalization in all segments of
the society. In her memoirs Savka
Dabčević Kučar comments on the
situation after the Brioni Plenum
saying, “As if we were now breathing
more freely.”32 Although Ranković had
been ousted and intelligence
services thoroughly reformed
expectations that all centralist
elements would disappear in
Yugoslavia were unrealistic. These
elements had been defeated but yet
omnipresent in all segments of the
society, at all levels of power and
in all parts of the country.
However, decentralization –
political and economic – was
jeopardized or questioned no more.
Decentralization, regretfully, did
not mean complete abandonment of all
centralist tendencies. Instead of
the federal center the state was
more and more thorn by six
republican centralisms. Many
controversies and all economic,
national and social differences –
not necessarily factors of
instability per se – surfaced
against a backdrop as such. The
country’s biggest problem became
people supposed to be act as its
leaders. Political elite was
disunited and state interests were
more and more held down in favor of
republican. Power struggle, concern
for own problems and disregard of
the problems facing others justified
Tito’s fears that decentralization
could easily lead towards
disintegration.
In the late 1960s
decision-makers – apart from
know-how - were more and more split
by regional, i.e. republican “key.”
Decentralization of economic policy
and introduction of the laws of free
market further emphasized
differences between Yugoslavia’s
developed and underdeveloped
republics. Unlike subventions that
often turned unprofitable, the
struggle for more favorable
investment and loans deepened
rivalry between enterprises
throughout Yugoslavia. The novelty
was banks replaced the state as key
players of financing and lending.
Banks were first of all other
economic factors that adjusted
themselves to market economy. To
them, profit was crucial rather than
interests of the country’s economy.
Accordingly, the new investment and
credit policy favored successful and
profit-making enterprises while
neglecting those that failed to find
their way in new circumstances.
Fully justified from a capitalist
point of view, in a socialist
society this was diametrically
opposite to initial wishes; and the
more so since most capital began
concentrating again in one place –
this time not in the federal
treasury but in several most
powerful central banks.
The state did
transfer some of its rights and
duties to the banking system but
still kept to itself the right to
participate in investment programs
though the so-called non-budget
balance of payment. By its own
criteria it continued financing (old
and new) project with these funds.
And those criteria, often
politically rather than economically
motivated, were factors that further
sharpened republics between
republics. Along with funds that
survived (such as the Fund for
Speedier Development of Less
Developed Regions) the moneys from
non-budget balance of payment were
straws to clutch at for all those
unable to produce good results on
their own. Reciprocity of this form
of solidarity was questioned as
crucial to further functioning of
the federation on equal footing.
Given that development of each and
every sociopolitical community
(municipality, province or republic)
was in reciprocal relationship with
economic results on its territory
competition in economic sphere moved
to political as well. In a socialist
state with a strong monopoly of one
party a specific federal system was
in causal relation with economic,
political and social problems.
Stable and even prosperous economic
situation in earlier periods
guaranteed social and political
peace. On the other hand, economic
crisis that started shaking the
Yugoslav society following the
economic reform in 1965 threatened
with turning into an open political
crisis with far-reaching
consequences. This is why solving of
accumulated economic problems had to
be placed at the priority list of
politics. Unfortunately, political
elite and economic experts mostly
failed to meet the criteria
necessary for pulling the country
out of crisis.
The wave of
student protests that swept over
almost all Yugoslav universities in
the first week of June 1968 was only
one of many signs warning that the
country was in a deep crisis. In
general public the crisis was being
mostly perceived through its
economic consequences (the fall in
living standard, growing
unemployment, etc.). However, the
economic crisis was in causal
relation with its deeper and deeper
political counterpart. Though not so
much visible to most citizens, and
especially not in its full intensity
and all of its forms, its escalation
threatened even the very survival of
the federation. The political crisis
was by far more dangerous than
negative trends in the economy. The
model (s) of the federation’s
functioning, economic and political
position of republics undergoing
economic and social reforms, and
relations between the “developed”
and “underdeveloped” were just some
of the issues highest officials were
growingly unable to reach consensus
on. Despite all the attempts to
resort to Aesopian hints so as to
assuage the crisis among the general
public, stormy meetings behind
closed doors indicated overt
antagonisms between individuals and
even the entire republican
leaderships. One of such meetings
was that of the Presidency of the EC
of LCY, chaired by Tito, held on
June 9, 1968. Members of the Serbian
leadership used the debate on
successes and failures of the
economic reform to complain against
their Zagreb colleagues. They
accused the Croatian leadership,
especially Mika Tripalo, of
undermining the principle of
democratic centralism by publicly
criticizing the federal bodies’
stands. They mostly referred to the
so-called May Consultations of the
CC of LCC (May 28-29, 1968) and
interviews some of Croatian leaders
gave to the media after it. Serbian
politician Dobrivoje (Bobi)
Radosavljević reproached the Croats
for openly accusing the Serbs of
still building unprofitable plants.
Some of them, he said, are important
for political rather than economic
reasons, but the problematic should
be nevertheless considered against a
larger economic-political background
and in a long run. “We are ready to
discontinue construction of every
facility,” he argued, adding
“However, we in Serbia are
hypothecated by old relations, by
the compromise between republican
leadership and these facilities are
a hypothecation of that compromise.”33
The problem of the so-called
political facilities was not the
only one, it was used just as a
paradigm. Critical remarks were also
about the Croatian leadership’s
practice of open polemics all other
problems of the economic reform,
such as the federation’s balance
sheet and foreign exchange regime.
He especially criticized the Croats
for using Tito as “a shelter” much
too often. “Comrade Tito, as we have
said on hundreds occasions, belongs
to all Yugoslav people, he
personifies our revolution and our
attainments…Comrades from Croatia
have to solve everything they
disagree with through dialogues with
other republics so that we find
mutual solutions in debates. One
cannot go to Tito to settle the
matters,” he warned.34 Representatives
from Montenegro (Đoko Pajković) and
Bosnia-Herzegovina (Rato Dugonjić)
sided with the Serbian leadership.
However, they criticized the methods
used by the Croatian leadership more
than what the latter had actually
said. Responding to all this, Savka
Dabčević-Kučar, minutely elaborated
the stances on (non)implementation
of economic reform taken by the
Croatian leadership. He pointed to
crumbling economy, inconsequent
foreign trade and foreign exchange
regimes, non-existence of clear-cut
and transparent accounts such as the
federation’s balance sheets, etc. To
end with, she said that in her
opinion speaking publicly about the
stances voted in by the Croatian
Assembly and Executive Committee
that were contrary to the decisions
taken by federal institutions were
not political subversion. This meant
not disagreement with the majority
or disrespect of democratic
centralism, she said, but an
obligation towards citizens of one’s
republic, the more so since after
each meeting of the Federal
Executive Council /SIV/ a brief
about a consensus reached on
decisions made was being issued.
Following her lengthy discussion
that clearly indicated many problems
undermining not only economic reform
but also federal relations, no one
denied her critical remarks.
Dobrivoje Radosavljević and Rato
Dugonjić just repeated their
criticism of going public. “In my
view, one should go public but
should first think twice when and
how, and try to settle everything
among leaderships,” said the Serbian
delegate while his counterpart from
Bosnia-Herzegovina wondered, “Can
one political leadership problem one
policy and fight for it without
having discussed in here first?”35
Neither of the two pointed a finger
at what was actually mistaken in the
policy proclaimed by the Croatian
leadership. This provoked Mika
Tripalo’s comment on the whole
discussion. “We haven’t heard any
argument that would deny some of our
basic political stands…I do not
claim that we are right about
everything we are saying, but let’s
then discuss contents, not methods.”36
Two statements by Jakov Blaževića
further sharpened the debate. He
first said that assaults at Tripalo
were in fact screened assaults
against the economic reform and Tito
in person.37 This provoked Petar
Stambolić to call for the
Presidency’s and EC CC LCY’s
distancing themselves from
Blažević’s statements as untrue.
Blažević’s second statement,
actually his rhetorical question
about how come that hotbeds of
crisis had not been identified, as
well as the people responsible for
student protests if the latter had
been known for years. Members of the
Serbian leadership realized that
they were actually on the carpet
list. Radosavljević said to Blažević
nervously, “Why don’t you, comrade
Jakov, come to Belgrade to govern,
as you are capable of assessing
everything? But you are sitting in
Zagreb and reading papers, and
conclude that the CC leadership is
opportunistic. None of us should be
just sitting here, so come on and
govern!”38 Petar Stambolić followed in
his footsteps in the same tone; he
criticized Blažević of not having
taken into consideration documents
of Serbia’s Presidency and EC of CC
of LCS while assessing the situation
but only statements given by some
individual leaders. He also
reproached the entire Croatian
leadership: at the moment student
protest broke out Zagreb enquired
whether demonstrations were
pro-Ranković or progressive. On the
basis of the official stance that
the protest was against the regime,
Stambolić drew the conclusion that
the enquiry suggested that the
Serbian leadership was seen as
conservative and, therefore,
protests against it could be either
pro-Ranković or progressive.39 As said
above, over this Croatian-Serbian
polemics Bosnian and Montenegrin
representatives made no bones about
what they agreed and what disagreed
with. Macedonian representative
Krste Crvenkovski tried to position
himself as an impartial observer
aware of failures of both sides but
appealing for unity in the interest
of the progress of the whole
country. The stance taken by
Slovenian representative France
Popit was more clear-cut. The same
as the Croatian leadership he
criticized elements of centralism
still visible in functioning of the
federal administration, and
emphasized the necessity placing
many powers from federal to
republican level. His motivation,
however, was not to provide support
to the Croatian leadership but to
advocate the interests that would
benefit his own republic. Sharp
statements heard at this meeting
indicated that cohesion of
Yugoslavia’s top political
leadership was considerably
undermined. More and more often,
like at this meeting, it was only
Josip Broz Tito’s authority that
could put an end to mutual
allegations and accusations. Apart
from documents, impressions by many
of those involved also indicate to
seriousness of the situation. In her
memoirs Savka Dabčević Kučar writes
about her flight on the way to this
meeting. While her plane was nearing
Belgrade a military aircraft
intercepted the plane so closely
that it lost altitude and its pilot
hit his head on the cabin’s roof.
Considering that never before had
military aircrafts “welcomed” planes
taking politicians to meetings, she
writes, “Have they, probably, wanted
to get rid of all of us, at once and
just by ‘chance’?”40
Antagonism between
Croatian and Serbian leaderships was
by far more complex than a
misunderstanding over one statement.
The problem was in their differing
perception of the goals of the
economic reform and, hence, in their
different understanding of
republics’ economic-political
standing within the federation.
Comments on the federation’s balance
sheets made by two of Serbia’s top
brass politicians best illustrate
these fundamental differences. While
transparent accounts were for Zagreb
condition sine qua not of the
federation’s sustainability and
guarantees of equality of its
constitutive parts, what bothered
Dobrivoje Radosavljević was that the
Croats were “carping on the issue
for months.”41 Draža Marković also
voiced his disagreement with
Croatian requests. He wrote in his
diary on May 17, 1968, “The
situation of balance sheets
(relations with the Croats, in fact)
is turning more and more
complicated. However, it’s good that
they remained isolated and will
surely have to withdraw.”42 Marković
was only partially right. The Croats
did remain alone since their
requests were outvoted in federal
institutions. On the other hand, he
was not exactly right in his
argument about their withdrawal. In
the line with democratic centralism
the Croats acknowledged the majority
vote but decided to take a step that
would cause the above-mentioned
stormy reactions. This time
frustration with the decision-making
procedure in Belgrade, especially
with the quality of these decisions,
spread beyond the small circle of
top leaders. Having realized that
support could not be obtained from
politicians the leadership of the SR
of Croatia turned to the general
public.
In late May 1968
(28-29) the EC of the CC of LCC
initiated consultations in Zagreb
(May Consultation) with
participation of political leaders
from all over Croatia. Though
presented as one in a row of
pre-congress debates the
consultation was mostly used for
informing the public about the
stands the Croatian leadership
considered incorrectly outvoted at
the federal level. In his address
Secretary of the EC Mika Tripalo
stressed out imperative disburdening
of the economy, which would make it
possible for working organizations
to operate more freely, enable
investment in modernization and
ensure higher salaries. Otherwise,
working organizations’ insolvency
would strengthen the monopoly of new
centers of economic power such as
banks and foreign trade or re-export
enterprises.43 Notwithstanding all
objectively aggravating
circumstances one of most
influential factors slowing down the
economic reform was the very League
of Communists, said Tripalo. “Devoid
of clear-cut prospects the League of
Communists manifests ideological
confusion as some of its highest
bodies are paralyzed,” said Tripalo.44
This was not for the first time that
he warned his colleagues that
settling the situation of their own
ranks preconditioned reformist
tendencies in the society.45 However,
this time he argued for a public
debate on the newly emerged problems
since the political leadership had
not found a solution to them.
“Saying that the debate has to be
public means not an open debate
within the party but the debate
involving the whole society, which
is the only way for truly socialist
and progressive forces to win out…A
discussion in forums behind closed
doors fundamentally hinders
attainment of that goal and leaves
negative political and social
side-effects on our country.”46 To end
with he stressed that consequent
implementation of the economic
reform implied certain changes in
the political system. This primarily
referred to a change in the
relationship between the federation
and republics, but also to further
improvements in inter-republic and
interethnic relations. In order to
make self-governing relations
stronger at all levels, said
Tripalo, the Croatian leadership
takes that many activities federal
institutions were implementing could
be transferred to self-governing
bodies and their administrative
divisions in republics and communes.
In response to the arguments that
suggestions as such were undermining
Yugoslavia, he said, “Yugoslavia is
not strengthened only by the federal
centre but by all its parts, and on
the basis of full equality of all
nations and their mutual
cooperation.”47 Although Tripalo’s
address already hinted true reasons
for convening the May consultation
meeting the very announcement that
Savka Dabčević-Kučar would address
it removed doubt. The Member of the
Presidency of CC of LCY and
President of the Republican
Executive Council was asked to
provide a more precise explanation
of the SIV press release saying that
all the republics had reached a
consensus on the federation’s
balance sheet on the one hand, and
the Croatian leadership’s well-known
opposite stand about the matter on
the other.48 The main problem, said
Dabčević-Kučar, was absence of
precise quantification of indicators
of the plan’s implementation and
non-implementation, which
preconditioned objective assessment
of results of the economic reform.
This was why the Croatian leadership
had asked to see the complete
balance sheet of the federation,
which implied the federal budget,
non-budget balance sheet, the
balance sheet of the General
Investment Fund, as well as the
balance sheet of foreign economic
relations. It turned out, however,
that authorized bodies had no system
for monitoring and registering
accounts that would have make it
possible to determine the exact
state of affairs in individual
sectors. Consequently, assessment of
the progress made and the plan for
the steps to be taken was brimming
with contradictions.49 At the SIV
session of May 17, 1968
representatives of other republics
had not accept critical remarks by
the Croatian leadership calling them
superfluous, and measures suggested
by the SIV sufficient for correction
of negative trends in 1967. Without
questioning the majority will
Dabčević-Kučar nevertheless warned
that the public was entitled to be
informed about Croatian stands as
well. The May Consultation was held
ten days later.
Although Serbian
politicians criticized their
Croatian colleagues the most saying
that it was solely about
Croatian-Serbian dispute would be
absurd and untrue. Anyway, the 5:1
ratio in major decision-making
clearly denies such a thesis. It
should be said that the said ratio
was mostly manifest when it came to
measures taken in economic policy
since the reasons behind them were
diametrically opposite to those for
taking political. In economic
matters too big differences in the
level of economic development
between Yugoslav republics and
provinces were decisive factors.
Slovenia, Croatia and Province of
Vojvodina were by many criteria
above the Yugoslav average, Serbia
without provinces was in the mean,
while Montenegro,
Bosnia-Herzegovina, Macedonia and
Province of Kosovo below the
average.
Such
constellation, to start with,
hindered a homogeneous approach to
resolution the country’s economic
problems. Before and even more after
the beginning of economic reforms
the underdeveloped had not been
capable of developing their
societies with their own funds and
resources. Therefore and despite a
general advocacy for political and
economic decentralization they had
still been vitally interested in
receiving funds from various federal
sources. Whether or not all deals
and transactions in the process were
fully transparent and economically
justified did not matter much to
them. On the other hand, the
developed saw the measures of
economic reforms and, especially,
decentralization as opportunities
for making even speedier progress.
The attempts at having the accounts
settled or the necessity to have the
state of accounts determined in
detail, and then also the modalities
for the use of mutual funds were
stroke the eye eve more against a
backdrop as such. All this did not
question further assistance to
underdeveloped regions; on the
contrary, Croatian politicians and
economists were proposing even more
funds to them, but this time through
instruments that would not be
contrary to reformist principles.50
Apart from leaderships of
underdeveloped republics the Croats
also perceived the federal
bureaucracy – above all SIV and
various departments and commissions
of the Federal Assembly – as major
straitjackets of the economic
reform.51 Overt disagreement with the
decisions by the highest executive
body was even more manifest in early
1968, at the above-mentioned
parliamentary debate on the
Resolution on the Principles of
Economic Policy in 1968. Although
they had managed to have the
decision on limiting contribution
rates annulled by then, their
dissatisfaction with functioning of
the federal administration remained
evident. Kiro Gligorov, the
vice-president of the Yugoslav
government and one of politicians
with biggest influence on shaping
the country’s economic policy, was
seen as ‘drum major’ of
anti-reformist forces. The meeting
of the closest circle of Croatian
politicians of April 6, 1968
provides a most illustrative
instance of the extent of animosity
for this Macedonian leader. A debate
on the state of affairs at Yugoslav
universities unavoidable led to a
debate on successes/failures of the
economic reform. In this context
Kiro Glogorov was mentioned as one
of most responsible individuals.
“The entire group assembled around
Kiro is a gang that should be chased
away,” argued Vladimir Bakarić to
what Mika Tripalo added, “Including
him in person although he somewhat
stands for the reform.”52 No one
obviously denied that Glogorov was
the one who introduced the economic
reform but, as time went by, people
became skeptical about the way he
was trying to put theory into
practice. Probably neither was the
fact that Kiro Gligorov represented
one of most underdeveloped Yugoslav
republics, which could have barely
benefited from consequent
implementation of reformist measures
overlooked. Savka Dabčević Kučar
carried the argument a step further:
she connected criticism of Gligorov
with his favoring of the solutions
proposed by Serbia.53 The fact that
Croat Mika Špiljak acted as the
president of the Yugoslav government
in 1968 further complicated rather
undermined relations between the
Croatian leadership and federal
institutions. Thorn between his
republic’s expectations and the
actual power balance in the
federation he more often than not
gave the upper hand to the latter in
decision-making. So he did in the
case of the federation’s balance
sheet. After many meeting at which
Croat stands were mostly outvoted,
in early summer of 1968, at
Špiljak’s request the Federal
Assembly gave a vote of confidence
to the SIV and, by doing it,
according to Tripalo, adopted the
untrue balance sheet of the
federation.54 Tito considerably
contributed to such denouement: he
wanted to lessen inter-republican
tensions and so put an end to the
debate on the balance sheet, calling
the latter “a problem of secondary
character.”55
The country’s bad
economic situation opened up yet
another “front” for competing
republics. Debates on which of them
scored worst in Yugoslavia’s overall
economic development intensified.
Since everyone documented his thesis
with statistical data, Stipe Šuvar
commented on the new situation
saying, “Inter-republican and
interethnic accounting is blooming,
while everyone presents the data
that suits him and gives voice to
his own version of the truth, which
he serves to his national community
often by using refined or else
underhand methods.”56 Indicatively,
not a single republic was satisfied
with the level and speed of its
economic growth; each saw itself as
deprived of this or that when
compared with the rest. Developed
republics were trying to prove that
their economic stagnation was in
discord with their potentials and
opportunities for development. Major
critical remarks were that
disproportionately large funds were
flowing from Ljubljana and Zagreb
into federal funds and that these
funds were irrationally distributed
to underdeveloped regions. The
monopoly of foreign export companies
and the so-called federal banks was
especially on the carpet list – they
were accused of having taken over
from the state “the role of an
expropriator of the surplus of
labor” from producers.57 On the other
hand, the underdeveloped complained
of economic position within the
federation. According to them, they
were the ones taken advantage of.
First, as they are sources of raw
materials that are then used by
industries of developed republics
under favorable conditions, and then
turned into markets for the
developed to sale their tariff-free
products, they argued.58 The measures
of economic reforms further
intensified the existing
contradictions in socioeconomic
relations, which, in turn, triggered
off open debates on equality of
Yugoslav republics and nations.
Though “defense of self-government”
was still quoted from political
rostrums as a main reason for
correction of disparities, the
thesis about defense of national
interests was spreading in the
public life. This was especially the
case in developed republics. So, for
instance, during student protests in
1968 Slovenian students and
politicians were stressing further
development of the system of higher
education as “a vital, national
problem” given that “unbearable
situation of education threatens
Slovenia’s development.”59
Several months
before the Belgrade-seated NIN
magazine published a summarized
version of the article President of
the Executive Council of SR of
Slovenia Stane Kavčič had written
for Theory and Practice (Teorija in
praksa) magazine. Referring to the
necessity for revaluation of the
roles of Yugoslav republics within
the federation he writes among other
things, “I would say that we, the
Slovenes, also have to think about
statehood – but, of course, the
statehood that would imply a modern,
organized society rather than be a
synonym for bureaucracy.” He argues
against the so-called federation of
communes – with its too many and
poorly mutually connected communes –
with the thesis about republics as
nation-states being more influential
within Yugoslavia. “In fact, this is
all about realization that some
issues concerning an entire nation
had to be settled in alliance with
others, and fight against such
localism that is irrational and
harmful to the nation as a whole. If
we have acknowledged nations and are
aware that they would be there for
long time to come, then we also have
to acknowledge that there could be
no state without a nation or
nations, and that those nations
cannot be indifferent to their own
surplus of labor…All this logically
implies that each republic has to be
provided bigger economic
competences.”60
4. ANOTHER REFORM OF THE
CONSTITUTION AND THE PARTY
Shortly after
initial measures of the economic
reform were implemented it became
evident that the SFRY Constitution
had to undergo changes: some
provisions of the federal
constitution were incompatible with
the tendency of intensive
decentralization of the society. The
process of building of a new
political and legal frame that would
enable attainment of the expected
objectives and results of the
economic reform in the interest of
all nations and national minorities,
and hence of the entire federation,
was launched. In April 1967 the
federal parliament adopted a package
of six initial constitutional
amendments.61 Though the contents of
these amendments were considerably
changed already next year, their
purpose was obvious: to “weaken” the
federation and strengthen
federalism. Instead of the Federal
Chamber all major powers were
invested in the Chamber of Peoples,
which further strengthened position
of constitutive elements of the
federation, i.e. republics and
provinces.62 Economic rights of the
federation were also limited in line
with basic principles of the
economic reform. The state’s still
present much too strong
interventionalism was moderated
under amendment 3 providing that
“the federation may participate,
with its own funds, only in
financing the investments in special
purposes as provided under the
federal legislation.”63 In late 1968,
at a joint session of the Federal
Chamber and the Chamber of Nations,
the Federal Assembly decided to
proclaim another 13 amendments.64
Among other
things, these amendments resulted in
more autonomy of provinces named
socialist autonomous provinces (SAP)
since, and turned into special
self-governing sociopolitical
communities entitled to
independently decide on relations
with the rest, determine sources of
their income and decide on their
organizational arrangements. Their
position was considerably equalized
with that of socialist republics.
While the 1963 Constitution listed
only republics as constitutive
elements of the federation, the 1968
amendments added yet another two
socialist provinces on the list.65
This provision did not provide the
right to self-determination and
secession that still belonged only
to “peoples of Yugoslavia.” No doubt
that the purpose of the
constitutional reform was more
far-reaching and complex than
improvement of the position of two
Yugoslav provinces and two biggest
national minorities. Another change
of the role of the Chamber of
Peoples illustrates how vital for
relations in the federation
inter-republican and interethnic
relations became at the time. Under
this new amendment this chamber
became predominant and biggest by
its membership, while the Federal
Chamber was extinguished.66 As usual
when crucial problems of the country
were on the agenda view on causes
and consequences of all changes were
rather contrary. According to some,
latest constitutional reforms were
unnecessary and coercive67, while the
others argued that they were
inadequate to a fundamental
transformation of the society.
Supporters of consequent
decentralization took that the
Constitution retained too many
elements of centralism, whereas
centralists argued strengthening of
republican “statehood” threatened
stability and integrity of
Yugoslavia. The fact that all
critical remarks were partially
justified was one of many signals
that it would be harder and harder
to reach a consensus on crucial
issues of Yugoslavia’s development
in the period to come.
Democratization
and decentralization of the society
such as Yugoslav were impossible
without appropriate changes in the
LCY. In this context, federalization
of the LCY was a vital element of
reform of the country’s leading
ideological-political power. The
Ninth Congress of LCY (March 11-15,
1969) was an attempt at securing
party organizations in republics the
same position constitutional
amendments had done for stronger
standing of republics. Basic
documents of the Congress –
including provisions of a new
Statute – put an emphasis on
independence and individualism of
republican organizations within the
unique LCY.68 While opposing
centralism these documents were
insisting on affirmation of the
national factor and, in parallel,
elimination of all elements of
centralism from further development
of the LCY.69 A changed schedule of
party congresses was an illustrative
example of decentralization of the
LCY. Until then a federal congress
had come as the first in a row while
congresses in republics followed. On
the eve of the Ninth Congress this
procedure was reversed: republican
congresses were held in the late
1968 and the federal one in March
1969.70 The change in schedule
indicated that a new political
paradigm was introduced. Republics
were no longer obliged to first hear
and then implements decisions made
at the federal level; from then on
stands were first harmonized at
republican levels while it was on
delegates at a federal congress to
confirm them. For the first time a
new leadership of the LCY was
elected by this procedure: members
of the leadership had been nominated
by republican congresses and their
nomination was confirmed at the
federal. The same as in the election
of delegates of the Chamber of
Nations, equal representation of all
the republics and provinces was
strictly observed in the election of
the highest party body.71 An efficient
executive body – to act as a kind of
collective leadership and collective
authority – had to be established to
ensure influence of republican
“policies” on the federal one.
Fifteen members of the Executive
Bureau included two outstanding
politicians from each republic and
one from each province, and Josip
Broz Tito.72 Many thought that the
Executive Committee was formed not
only for the sake of efficiency and
authority but for various unspoken
reasons. Latinka Perović writes that
Mijalko Todorović, the secretary of
the EC of the CC of LCY, was the one
who initiated the whole project.
Faced with growing decentralization
of the country Todorović saw a
factor of stability and synthesis in
a party center that would include
highest politicians from every
republic and province. Besides such
powerful composition of a collective
leadership, in his opinion, would be
a guarantee against Tito’s personal
dominance in the party.73 Though this
thesis was not so explicitly
elaborated to him, Tito’s inherent
instinct for political survival put
an end to this course of action; on
the contrary, as time went by the
collective leadership became an
amorphous body in the proceedings of
which Tito was participating less
and less frequently. Instead of
agreements agreed on by people
sitting around one table, most of
crucial decisions were more and more
frequently made in direct
communication with Tito.
Expert and
political debates on the last set of
constitutional amendments began in
the late 1970s. While all
constitutions that far were putting
emphasis on sociopolitical
arrangement the pressing problems
facing the country now suggested
that Yugoslav federalism should be
on the agenda too. The view that the
federation had to be reformed
prevailed despite many different
opinions about the character and
depth of changes to be made.
Following “a patient and toilsome
harmonization of views,” as Mika
Tripalo put it, and a public debate
the Federal Assembly passed another
23 amendments of the 1963
Constitution on June 30, 1971. New
amendments for the first time
conditioned the country’s
sustainability and progress with
national question without neglecting
the class one. According to
Croatia’s renowned legal expert Leon
Geršković, the reform was supposed
to ensure “constitution of a nation
as a socioeconomic community and its
statehood expressed by the political
system that makes constitution of
such community possible.”74 This (new)
system implied intervention into the
fundamental issue of the
federation’s functioning – the issue
of sovereignty. Unlike earlier
constitutions authorizing the
federation to protect sovereignty of
republics, new amendments
“nationalized their sovereignty,”
i.e. conveyed this authority from
the federation to republics. So
Amendment 20 provides that the SFRY
is a federation as a state community
of voluntarily united peoples and
their socialist republics, and that
a republic is “a state based on
sovereignty of people.”75 Other
amendments also followed this trend:
redistribution of federal powers to
republics.76 Only political and
economic rights that were explicitly
quarantined under the Constitution
were left to the Federation.
Croatian and Slovenian leaderships’
years-long criticism of the
so-called alienated centers of power
(in Belgrade) and the federal
center’s nontransparent investment
policies received recognition in
Amendment 34 providing that the
Federation “shall not establish
funds and undertake obligations
unless so authorized under the SFRY
Constitution or assemblies of
republics and autonomous provinces
agree with establishment of such
funds or obligations to be
undertaken.”77 The role of the federal
state was also weakened by a new
authority (along with the
presidential office) whose
functioning would be fully manifest
only after Josip Broz Tito’s death.
The said authority was the SFRY
Presidency, “a collective head of
state,” chaired by representatives
of republics and provinces – by
turns.
Although passed in
the summer of 1971 it was only in
1972 that the amendments to the SFRY
Constitution began to be
implemented. Main reason for such
“postponement” was a political
crisis followed by the dramatic
denouement of the situation in
Croatia in late 1971. Accused of
tolerating and supporting
nationalism, the Croatian political
leadership -whose longstanding
struggle for reform of the
federation actually resulted in the
amendments and then in a new
Yugoslav constitution in 1974 - was
discharged.
5. CONCLUSION
With consent of
all republican assemblies, the
Chamber of Nations of the Federal
Assembly proclaimed a new SFRY
Constitution on February 21, 1974.
That was the longest constitution in
the whole world: it had more words
and articles even than the
Constitution of India. However,
considering specificities of the
Yugoslav sociopolitical system, it
was at the same time among the most
complex constitutions.78 Although it
adopted all the solutions provided
in the amendments passed in 1967,
1968 and 1971, federalism remained
in its foreground. Sovereignty of
republics and provinces was
additionally emphasized in the
constitutional preamble saying,
“Having taken into consideration
every nation’s right to
self-determination, including
secession too, the peoples of
Yugoslavia united in a federation…”79
A newly structured federal assembly
also ensured more important roles to
republics. Five parliamentary
chambers were replaced by two only –
the Chamber of Republics and
Provinces and the Federal Chamber.
Though reform of the federation
called for further decentralization
of the state and society, no
progress was made towards
(political) democratization; on the
contrary, the Constitution
explicitly provided and even
strengthened the predominant roles
to the League of Communist and Josip
Broz Tito.80 While the power invested
in other institutions was being
restricted, Tito’s was growing. That
was one of paradoxes of the Yugoslav
society undergoing modernization and
liberalization while ensuring one
man’s authoritarianism. Though
already an old man, Tito had no
intention to give up any power
invested in him since the end of the
WWII. Twenty years later he was
still a head of state, party
president and supreme commander.
Besides, against the backdrop of
growing disunity of political elites
he took upon himself to act as an
unavoidable “supranational” arbiter.
The AVNOJ decision
(1943) about Yugoslavia as a
federation launched a lengthy and
occasionally rather turbulent
building of a socialist federation.
While during the first twenty years
the concept of federalism was in the
back seat, the role of constitutive
members of the federation was a
predominant topic of debates
throughout the last twenty years (of
Yugoslavia’s existence). And yet –
and despite all constitutional
amendments and compromises made –
the question about how genuine
federation Yugoslavia actually was
remains open. Outstanding
international theoreticians of
federalism do not think as one about
it. “Once it was almost impossible
to find a federation in the whole
world the views about its
fundamental nature were so
opposing.”81 Questioning the very
possibility of federalism in
authoritarian, one-party systems,
some theoreticians tend towards
seeing the case of Yugoslavia as
“façade federalism,”
“quasi-federalism” or “a federation
of one-party states.” One the other
hand, for some experts Yugoslavia
was a striking proof that federalism
was possible even in communism. And
that’s not all. They argued that
provisions of the 1974 Constitution
made it possible for Yugoslavia to
grow into a confederation.82
Criticized from
different motives and revised twice
(in 1981 and 1988) the 1974 SFRY
Constitution remained Yugoslavia’s
last socialist constitution. Denied
as a whole by some and considered a
warrant of national independence by
other, the document providing
preconditions for and ways of
integration became a crucial element
of disintegration. Instead of
“flexing” the Yugoslav federation
entered the phase of dismantlement
in the 1980s.
Sources and Literature
SOURCES
1. AJ, Arhiv Jugoslavije, Beograd,
Srbija
Fond 507, Savez komunista
Jugoslavije
Kabinet Predsjednika Republike (KPR)
Fond 130, Savezno izvršno veće
2. HDA, Hrvatski državni arhiv,
Zagreb, Hrvatska
Fond 1220, Centralni komitet Saveza
komunista Hrvatske
LITERATURE
1.
BAKARIĆ, Vladimir, Socijalistički
samoupravni sistem i društvena
reprodukcija (I-IV),
Informator/Mladost/Svjetlost,
Zagreb/Sarajevo 1983.
2.
BILANDŽIĆ, Dušan, Borba za
samoupravni socijalizam u
Jugoslaviji 1945-1969, Institut za
historiju radničkog pokreta
Hrvatske, Zagreb 1969.
3.
BILANDŽIĆ, Dušan, Historija SFRJ,
Školska knjiga, Zagreb 1978.
4.
BILANDŽIĆ, Dušan, Hrvatska moderna
povijest, Golden marketing, Zagreb
1999.
5.
Comparative Communism. The Soviet,
Chinese and Yugoslav Models (ed.
Gary K. Bertsch and Thomas W.
Ganschow), W. H. Freeman and
Company, San Francisco 1976.
6.
Contemporary Yugoslavia. Twenty
Years of Social Experiment (ed.
Wayne S. Vucinich), University of
California Press, Berkeley and Los
Angeles 1969.
7.
CRAMPTON, Richard, Balkan posle
Drugog svetskog rata, Clio, Beograd
2003.
8.
DABČEVIĆ KUČAR, Savka, '71. –
hrvatski snovi i stvarnost (1-2),
Interpublic, Zagreb 1997.
9.
Deveti kongres Saveza komunista
Jugoslavije, Beograd 1969.
10.
Dokumenti. Jun – lipanj 1968.,
Praxis, Zagreb 1971.
11.
DRAGOVIĆ, Ivan, Brionski plenum, GMT
Servis, Beograd 2002.
12.
ĐUKIĆ, Slavoljub, Slom srpskih
liberala, Filip Višnjić, Beograd
1990.
13.
GERŠKOVIĆ, Leon, Ustavne teme,
Zagreb, 1976.
14.
HOLJEVAC, Većeslav, Hrvati izvan
domovine, Matice hrvatska, Zagreb
1967.
15.
HORVAT, Branko, Ogled o
jugoslavenskom društvu, Mladost,
Zagreb 1969.
16.
KARDELJ, Edvard, Beleške o našoj
društvenoj krizi, Kultura, Beograd
1966.
17.
KARDELJ, Edvard, Nacija i
međunarodni odnosi, BIGZ, Beograd
1975.
18.
KARDELJ, Edvard, O sistemu
samoupravnog planiranja. Brionske
diskusije, Radnička štampa, Beograd
1976.
19.
KARDELJ, Edvard, Slobodni udruženi
rad. Brionske diskusije, Radnička
štampa, Beograd 1978.
20.
KAVČIČ, Stane, Dnevnik in spomini
(1972-1987.), Ljubljana 1988.
21.
LUKIĆ, Vojin, Brionski plenum –
Obračun sa Aleksandrom Rankovićem,
Stručna knjiga, Beograd 1990.
22.
MADŽAR, Ljubomir, Suton
socijalističkih privreda, Ekonomika
i Institut ekonomskih nauka, Beograd
1990.
23.
MARKOVIĆ, Dragoslav Draža, Život i
politika 1967 – 1978. (1-2),
Izdavačka radna organizacija „Rad“,
Beograd 1987.
24.
MECANOVIĆ, Ivan, Jugoslavenski
ustavi, Zagreb 1986.
25.
MUJADŽEVIĆ, Dino, Bakarić. Politička
biografija, Zagreb, 2011.
26.
NIKEZIĆ, Marko, Srpska krhka
vertikala, Helsinški odbor za
ljudska prava u Srbiji, Beograd
2003.
27.
PERIĆ, Ivan, Nacionalizam na
prostoru bivše Jugoslavije, Zagreb
2005.
28.
Primjene federalnog načela i pouke
ustavne reforme 1971. (ur. Branko
Smerdel), Zagreb, 2007.
29.
PEROVIĆ, Latinka, Zatvaranje kruga:
ishod političkog rascepa u SKJ
1971/1972., Svjetlost, Sarajevo
1991.
30.
PETRANOVIĆ, Branko, Istorija
Jugoslavije 1918 – 1978., Nolit,
Beograd 1981.
31.
PETRANOVIĆ, Branko, ŠTRBAC, Čedomir,
Istorija socijalističke Jugoslavije
(knjiga treća), Radnička štampa,
Beograd 1977.
32.
Povijest Saveza komunista
Jugoslavije, Izdavački centar
Komunist/Narodna knjiga/Rad, Beograd
1985.
33.
REPE, Božo, PRINČIČ, Jože, Pred
časom. Portret Staneta Kavčiča,
Modrijan, Ljubljana 2009.
34.
RUSINOW, Dennison, The Yugoslav
Experiment 1948-1974, University of
California Press, Berkeley and Los
Angeles 1978.
35.
RUSINOW, Dennison, Yugoslavia:
Oblique Insights and Observations,
University of Pittsburgh Press,
Pittsburgh 2008.
36.
Savjetovanje u Centralnom komitetu
Saveza komunista Hrvatske 28. i 29.
Svibnja 1968. godine, Informativna
služba CK SKH, Zagreb 1968.
37.
SIROTKOVIĆ, Jakov, Ekonomski razvoj
Jugoslavije. Od prosperiteta do
krize, Narodne novine, Zagreb, 1990.
38.
ŠEFER, Berislav, Ekonomski razvoj
Jugoslavije i privredna reforma,
Stručna štampa, Beograd 1969.
39.
Šesti kongres Saveza komunista
Hrvatske. Zagreb, 5-7.XII 1968.
Stenografske bilješke (I-III),
Komunist, Zagreb 1969.
40.
ŠUVAR, Stipe, Nacije i
međunacionalni odnosi, Naše teme,
Zagreb 1970.
41.
The Changing Face of Communism in
Eastern Europe (ed. Peter A. Toma),
The University of Arizona Press,
Tucson 1970.
42.
TRIPALO, Miko, Hrvatsko proljeće,
Globus, Zagreb 1990.
43.
TRIPALO, Miko, Uloga i zadaci Saveza
komunista u provođenju ekonomske
politike i razvijanju
socijalističkih društvenih odnosa.
XIX konferencija Saveza komunista
grada Zagreba, Zagreb 1965.
44.
Ustav Socijalističke Federativne
Republike Jugoslavije, Sekretarijat
za informacije Savezne skupštine,
Beograd 1974.
45.
Ustav Socijalističke Federativne
Republike Jugoslavije, Službeni list
SFRJ, Beograd 1971.
46.
VUKOVIĆ, Zdravko, Od deformacija SDB
do Maspoka i liberalizma, Narodna
knjiga, Beograd 1989.
47.
ZEČEVIĆ, Miodrag, Početak kraja
SFRJ. Stenogram i drugi prateći
dokumenti proširene sednice Izvršnog
komiteta CK SKJ održane od 14. do
16. marta 1962. godine, Arhiv
Jugoslavije/Printer komerc, Beograd
1998.
|