Introduction
The creation of
Yugoslavia was not motivated by
economic or even social development,
but its establishment was rather to
serve the usual reasons of the state
- above all security, but also
equity. The latter, understood as
the fulfillment of national – in the
sense of ethnic – rights and
objectives, was also the basis for
its legitimacy. However, no durable
agreement was ever reached on the
constitutional framework of its
national and Yugoslav legitimacy. In
the pursuit of an equitable solution
to its national issues, the country
was in a state of perpetual crisis
of legitimacy. This unfulfilled
nationalism blocked its
democratization and resulted in the
adoption of misguided decisions,
among others also in the domain of
economic policy.
Both the economic
and political history of Yugoslavia
consists of a series of ill-advised
constitutional decisions and then
intermittent attempts to implement
necessary reforms so as to rectify
these decisions. These decisions
would regularly go on to prove
themselves as untenable since they
were guided by the same, mainly
ethnic or national motives. Some
form of dictatorship was always seen
as justified, above all from the
perspective of security. And then
one form or other of territorial
devolution was used to seek out
equity for national-territorial and
economic interests.
At the same time,
the external circumstances were not
favorable. The country needed (i) a
liberal-democratic constitution in
an era of rising nationalism; (ii)
the development of a
private-ownership-based economy open
for exchange with the world in a
time of growing protectionism and
totalitarianism and (iii) the rule
of law in revolutionary times.
Favorable conditions for
liberalization and democratization
occurred only on the eve of the
country’s dissolution.
During the last
couple of decades after the
break-up, seven ex-Yugoslav states
co-exist within a system of regional
cooperation that suffers from the
same shortcomings as the former
common state. Thus the current
situation seems as temporary and
unnatural as any of the Yugoslav
structures from the inception of the
common state to its disappearance.
Even though the
common state was conceived as a
project in modernization, both
national and social, the overall
consequence of the Yugoslav
political and economic explorations,
which regularly brought about
short-lived and misguided solutions,
was backwardness, and not only
economic at that. This failure
should not be taken as proof against
the project itself since neither
before nor after the existence of
Yugoslavia have political
instability and a general lagging
behind been removed. But history is
not suitable for counterfactual
evaluation, except when speculating
about the future. In real time,
let’s say towards the end of the
1980s, the project of a democratic
Yugoslavia was not inferior to its
nationalist alternatives measured by
what could be expected from those
alternatives. But nationalisms
prevailed, and this is now history,
which needs to be explained. That
the fall was so steep represents a
challenge to that explanation. But
that is a matter of political choice
and not historical inevitability.
This text will
deal with a historical overview of
Yugoslavia’s economic development
and economic policy, with attention
focusing on the period after 1948.
First, I’ll set out the theoretical
framework then I’ll show the most
significant institutional and
developmental characteristics, then
outline above all the fiscal
dilemmas of the joint state and
finally, sketch out the economic
development after the dissolution,
that is, during the last few
decades. Separately, in short
asides, I’ll focus on the financial
crisis, the collapse of economic
reforms from the 1960s, the
stagnation of the 1980s, the unequal
development of the new states, and
the creation of a common market in
2006.
Politics between Nationalism and
Liberalism
Political history
is not completely positivistic since
it is based at least on the tacit
assumption that there are certain
durable regularities, if not
full-scale historical laws. These
regularities exist for two reasons.
One is the perpetual problems faced
by those who make political
decisions. On the one hand, there is
the need to secure a certain level
of public goods, above all security,
and on the other, there are changing
circumstances, which require
adjustability in carrying out
political objectives. The other
reason is that constitutional or
other government solutions constrain
the available set of means which can
be used to resolve durable political
problems in changing external and
internal circumstances. This
primarily concerns the
constitutional framework that is the
basis for legitimacy, regardless of
the fact how much support one
government or another, one holder of
office or another actually has.
On the other hand,
economic history is at least
partially autonomous in relation to
political decisions and, in fact, is
part of the changing circumstances
that have to be taken into account
in decision-making since both
objectives and especially available
means are subject to change. This is
due to both the development of
technology and changes in the
significance and character of
external economic relations. Foreign
trade and public finances are
undoubtedly of great significance
for small countries and small
economies. Yugoslavia was certainly
a small country, at least from the
economic perspective. Even more so
are the post-Yugoslav countries that
emerged after the break-up of the
common state.
Bearing in mind
the political circumstances and the
economic development of the 20th
century, Yugoslavia represented a
political solution from the
standpoint of the basic political
problem, the problem of security as
a public good. The problem it
perpetually faced, however, lay in
the discrepancy between the
nationalist conception of politics
and the economic need for liberal
relations both internally and
externally. Consequently, the state
could not secure the desired level
of equity and justice and was
confronted with social discontent
regarding the level and distribution
of wealth.
On the one hand,
the country was supposed to
reconcile the nationalist conception
of equity with the liberal demands
of economic development. The latter,
in turn, spurred social discontent.
The country fell apart when
nationalism became the political
expression of social
dissatisfaction. At the same time,
the liberal-democratic alternative
was rejected. After the break-up,
the sluggish and indecisive
democratization and liberalization
were the cause of a relatively
unsatisfactory political and
economic development, partly also
due to misguided economic policy.
Therefore, the
discord between nationalist
objectives and liberal means is,
simply put, the reason behind the
perpetual instability of the
Yugoslav state and the practically
constant adoption of misguided, or
at best, short-sighted political
solutions.
A General Overview
of Development
The data on
Yugoslavia’s development is not
unknown and therefore it is
unnecessary to go into detail. Image
1 shows the GDP per capita in steady
dollars. From 1921 to the outbreak
of World War II, the country was not
characterized by any exceptional
economic progress. In that, however,
it was no different from the
majority of neighboring countries,
whether it be, for example, Greece,
Hungary or Bulgaria. Partly this was
the consequence of demographic
growth, but since we are talking
about several decades, it is clear
that on the whole the economy was
stagnant and that it is not possible
to talk about any significant
progress in relation to economic
development on Yugoslav territory in
the time before the establishment of
the common state.
Image 1:
Yugoslavia, GDP per capita, steady dollar
Source: Maddison database
Development in the
years after World War II, if we put
aside the years of the Soviet
blockade, is characterized by
significant economic growth and
development, if the latter is
expressed, again, by the per capita
GDP. While in the first twenty years
or so the GDP per capita increased
just under 40 percent, in the period
from 1952 to 1979 it increased just
under 5 times. As in both cases it
was a matter of rebuilding the
country after great war devastation,
there is no doubt that Yugoslavia
after World War II achieved an
incomparably better economic
development than it did after World
War I. Of course, one has to bear in
mind that economic development the
world over was much faster, and not
only compared to the development in
the period between the two great
wars, but was in fact much faster
than in any previous period in
history – at least to the degree
that such comparisons are at all
possible.
This can also be seen by comparison
with neighboring countries, all of
which had successful economic growth
in the period after World War II,
before the end of 1970 and in the
decade that followed. Irrespective
of statistical problems, due to
which comparisons are not always
fruitful, there is no doubt that,
for example, Greece, Hungary and
Bulgaria, not to mention the more
developed countries of Western
Europe, also had accelerated
economic growth and development.
In fact, the 1980s are the key here.
Namely, in that period all socialist
countries, including Yugoslavia,
underwent economic stagnation and
decelerated growth. This can also be
seen in Table 1. In the period from
1979 to 1989 there is actually zero
growth of per capita income. A
similar situation prevailed in
neighbouring Bulgaria and Hungary,
but, for example, not in Greece. And
if to this group we add Austria, it
becomes completely clear that this
stagnation was not a consequence of
European, much less world, economic
trends. In order to understand the
break-up of Yugoslavia, this is
certainly the most important
political and economic period.
This is followed by the 1990s,
which, up to 1993-1994, brought a
reduction of economic activity by
about roughly a half, even though it
was about a third smaller than in
the years 1979, 1989 and 1999.
Recovery begins again after 2000 –
and for all ex-Yugoslav countries
together it is such that on the
whole the levels from 1979 and 1989
are reached again. Nevertheless, one
has to bear in mind the demographic
changes, which are now negative, for
a part of the population was lost
due to the wars, due to a negative
birthrate, and due to emigration.
All the same, when the GDP per
capita is in question, for about
thirty years, for all ex-Yugoslav
states taken together, it barely
marked an increase. In other words,
the country or countries had
stagnated for practically three
decades.
Finally, economic development ground
to a halt or was significantly
slowed down – if not completely
negative – after 2008, as a
consequence of the global financial
crisis. Some ex-Yugoslav states
fared better than others – which in
itself neccessitates an explanation.
In this context, the role of the
liberalization of trade both with
the European Union, as well as
regionally by the establishment of a
regional free trade zone known as
CEFTA (Central European Free Trade
Agreement), was of great
significance. The European Union had
opened its market to those
ex-Yugoslav countries that had not
joined the EU like Slovenia in 2001.
CEFTA, in turn, had inherited
bilateral free trade agreements when
it was established in 2006. In any
case, one cannot stress enough the
importance of foreign trade for
these very small ex-Yugoslav
economies.
In the century between the
establishment of Yugoslavia and the
present, development was either slow
or unsustainable. In the entire
period, however, there was no
political stability either in
Yugoslavia, or between the newly
independent states, and not even
within them internally. And this
irrespective of the great, in
reality revolutionary, changes and
independently of the different
constitutional reforms and political
changes, including changes in
economic policy. The common country,
as well as the independent states,
did not aspire towards
democratization, while
liberalization measures were often
confronted by suspicion about who
was better and who worse off.
Non-democratic solutions and the
non-liberal economic policy
temporarily contributed to
stabilization, but in the long run
they signified the abandonment of a
more durable political community.
The consequence of this discord
between nationalist interests and
liberal means of economic
development is the long-term lagging
behind of the Yugoslav countries.
There is no simple explanation for
this stagnation. Geographically,
Yugoslavia is in the immediate
vicinity of the developed world, so
this backwardness, if one can call
it such, could not be explained by
geographic isolation from the
advanced part of the world.
Moreover, at least at the time of
stagnation during the 1980s,
external circumstances in fact
favored the political changes that
were necessary in order for the
country to join the developed part
of the world. So that the lack of
development and lagging behind,
especially during the last forty
years, can only be explained by the
decisions made by the Yugoslav
authorities, the authorities of the
Yugoslav republics and autonomous
provinces, and the authorities of
the newly independent states – and
not in the last resort by the
citizens.
Regional Differences
Bearing in mind the permanent
instability of the country, it is
not unimportant to see whether
dissatisfaction was based on the
enduring bias of the political and
economic system towards one or
another region. Again, the data for
development after World War II is
better and more easily compared than
the data for the period between the
two great wars. Also, it can be
analyzed more or less in detail.
Still, a rough picture of
comparative development can be
gained on the basis of differences
in per capita income.
Table 1
Per capita national product in 1910, US dollar (1970 value)
Source:
Palairet, The Balkan Economy. CUP,
1997. pp. 233.
For the period before the
establishment of Yugoslavia there
are varying assessments of
differences in development and one
of these is given in Table 1. The
data for Slovenia and Macedonia is
missing, but the differences in
development could not have been too
great because even the differences
in relation to Austria and the Czech
Republic are not as great as they
would be later. In any case,
regional differences, which were to
dominate the (economic and
political) debates in both
Yugoslavias, do not appear to be
such as to represent an
insurmountable obstacle to creating
a common state.
For the period between the two wars
the quality of the data leaves
something to be desired. This was
due, among other things, to frequent
changes in internal regions.
Probably the most influential was
the claim by Rudolf Bićanić that
more developed regions, which had
been a part of Austria-Hungary
before the unification (of
Yugoslavia), were paying higher
agrarian land tax rates than Serbia,
Montenegro and Dalmatia. Table 2
provides a cumulative review for the
period before the Great Economic
Depression.
Table 2
Land tax,
1919-1928
Source:
Bicanic
Differences in tax burdens wouldbe
the subject of political disputes
throughout the entire history of
Yugoslavia as the common country. An
additional subject of disagreement
was the expenditure of public funds
in which it was usually claimed that
greater investments are being poured
into less developed areas – that is,
into Serbia between the two wars –
and fewer into the more developed.
As agriculture was the dominant
economic activity in the first
Yugoslavia, data on different
agrarian land tax burdens is
undoubtedly significant. It is
important to note that with time the
budget was less dependent on
indirect taxes – which included
agrarian land tax – and that these
made up about 50 percent of the
budget immediately after the
establishment of the common state,
falling to about a third of overall
tax revenue before World War II,
while the share in the budget from
immediate taxes and revenues from
state enterprises went up. Before
the war the overall sum of the
latter was just below from what it
was from indirect taxes.
The main objection during that
period, however, was that the tax
burden of the more developed areas
had increased in the transition from
Austria-Hungary to the Yugoslav
state. This undoubtedly continued to
be a hot topic later as well when
tax burdens in Yugoslavia were
compared to the ones in the newly
independent states. It must be said
that it is not unexpected that a new
state should invest more in its
underdeveloped areas because it is
reasonable to expect that regional
differences should decrease after
state unification. After all, this
is the key economic rationale in
establishing any common state.
Therefore, this was to become the
second most important topic of
debate – could Yugoslavia secure the
kind of economic growth that would
lead to an evening-out of the level
of economic growth in all of its
regions, could it lead to a
convergence in the per capita income
levels?
The data is not reliable in the case
of the first Yugoslavia, but since
the overall growth was modest, it
would not be realistic to expect
that a particularly significant
increase of regional differences had
taken place. Besides, if and to the
degree that it happened, the effects
of negative international economic
trends would in all likelihood have
to be greater than any domestic
redistribution of funds. This, of
course, doesn’t change the substance
of the problem of equity, both as
regards the less developed as well
as the more developed regions
because all expectations are that,
in the long run, the state would
secure a convergence of the levels
of per capita income between the
regions. To put it another way, it
would be reasonable to expect that
less developed areas have faster
economic growth than more developed
areas in order to even out the
levels of the standard of living
throughout the country.
It is not very likely that this
occurred in the first Yugoslavia,
but the interesting question here is
whether the second Yugoslavia
secured faster economic growth for
the less developed republics and
provinces? This is the subject of
enormous amounts of research, but
the rough and very general answer is
not particularly contentious. In
other words, there was no obvious
convergence in economic development
between the particular regions. This
can be seen from Table 3.
Table 3:
Gross Domestic Product per capita
(Slovenia = 100, unless otherwise
indicated)
Notes:
1) Data for 1997. refer to gross
material product per capita for all
Yugoslav republics (including
Kosovo) and gross domestic product
for other countries. – 2) The actual
GDP per capita (in USD according to
the exchange rate) for Slovenia and
the hypothetically achievable level
of GDP per capita (in USD according
to the exchange rate) for other
republics, assuming that the
differences in the region (measured
according to the GDP per capita) are
the same as in 1989.
Source:
The Vienna Institute for
International Economic Studies
for 1997 and 1999 and the OECD for
other years.
Slovenia’s GDP per capita equals
100. As can be seen from the table,
the Croatian per capita GDP was
about two thirds of Slovenia’s, the
Serbian about half, the autonomous
province of Vojvodina’s about 60
percent, while the other republics
and provinces trailed behind with
roughly a third of Slovenia’s per
capita GDP. Kosovo lagged behind
mainly because of its high birth
rate – but its overall (economic)
growth rate was even a little higher
than in other parts of the country.
The less developed regions underwent
slower progress in the first period
after 1952, which, at least in part,
was due to isolation from external
markets after the introduction of
the so-called Iron Curtain. It is
also important to note that there
were no further negative
consequences as regards their
development, especially if one takes
into account the demographic
changes, after the changes in the
economic system in the mid-1960s.
Generally speaking, one could not
say that Yugoslavia had managed to
secure convergent development for
different parts of the country. In
fact, particularly after the
systemic changes in the mid-1960s,
it seems that regional development,
in better and worse times, was
fairly balanced. Regional
differences were not small – with
the exception of Kosovo, up to a
ratio of 1 to 3 – but such
differences are not unheard of in
many complex countries. However, the
fact that over time they did not
change significantly, and
particularly that they were not
significantly reduced, points to
systemic deficiencies and also
challenges the economic rationale of
the political, especially the
nationalist, disputes - the latter
particularly if one takes into
account the difference in employment
and unemployment. Table 4 gives the
rates of unemployment from 1952 to
just before the break-up.
Table 4:
Unemployment
rate in %
Source:
OECD.
It is clear from the above that the
less developed areas were, partly
due to higher demographic activity,
much worse off in terms of the labor
market than the developed areas. In
truth, the high unemployment rate
that was especially prominent in the
1980s has remained a structural
economic characteristic for the
majority of the new independent
states to this day. The causes are
surely not the same, at least not
entirely. It is important to point
to the durability of low employment
and high unemployment even in
Croatia after it became independent,
but it is particularly important to
do so in the other regions and
states. Slovenia is an exception
here – and this is of notable
significance in explaining the
dissolution of the common country –
because Slovenia was a leader among
the secessionists, at least from
around 1988. This casts doubt on the
explanation for the country’s
break-up, which states that it is to
be found in Yugoslavia’s economic
failure and the failure of its
economic system, which was biased in
favor of the underdeveloped regions
and against the more developed ones.
Image 2:
National
income per capita
Source:
Maddison database
After the break-up of the country,
there was a great increase in
regional differences, that is, in
differences pertaining to the
economic activity of the states that
emerged from Yugoslavia. Table 3
also gives the state of affairs at
the end of the 1990s, when these
differences, due to the consequences
of the wars, were the greatest. In
the meantime there came about a
relative convergence, which can
partly be discerned from Image 2,
but nevertheless today's differences
are greater than in any period of
Yugoslav history and if one is to
believe the data from admittedly not
very reliable sources, regional
differences were also smaller before
the establishment of the common
state in 1918.
All in all, Yugoslavia was not a
country with convergent economic
development, but neither was it
particularly biased, negatively or
positively, towards the less
developed areas, at least if we are
to judge by the growth of the per
capita income. The overall
development, expressed as per capita
income, can be seen pretty clearly
in Image 2. The differences between
the republics did not change
significantly (Kosovo is the
exception due to its demographic
growth), and then increased in
relation to Slovenia and later in
relation to Croatia as well, while
the others converged, especially
with Serbia.
Concerning employment and social
development, the less developed
areas were on the whole lagging
behind. A more detailed analysis
would certainly show that
development in different segments
and particular fields was not
unequivocal, especially where
education and the development of
industrial production are concerned,
but this would not be of crucial
importance in explaining stability
and the sustainability of the
economy and the state.
Reform and Deadlock
Most attention has probably been
focused on studying the
self-management system and the
economic reforms of the mid-1960s.
The motivation was as much political
as it was economic. Finances from
abroad also played an important
role, as did bilateral aid and
multilateral credits and finally
access to the foreign financial
market. The political limitation was
maintenance of the one-party
monopoly of power.
Generally speaking, socialist
reforms followed the strategy –
first economic, and then political
reform - in other words, first
liberalization of the market, and
then democratization. The program of
the League of Communists of
Yugoslavia from 1958 contains a
clear ranking of alternative
systems. A multi-party democracy was
more acceptable than the Soviet
system if socialist self-management
and non-party pluralism proved to be
unsustainable, in the sense that
they are neither economically nor
politically more progressive than
alternative systems. One could,
therefore, say that democratization
was seen as the political exit
strategy if it turned out that there
was no other way to maintain
political stability and economic
development.
One problem was the nationalization
of investments. A key systemic
difference between capitalism and
socialism was – and as a matter of
fact, still is – who initiates
investment decisions? The
nationalization of assets was the
precondition for the state to
monopolize investment decisions.
Investments were financed from the
profits of companies that were in
state ownership on the basis of a
central plan. This is the very
essence of the Soviet system which
was established by Stalin’s
collectivization and nationalization
of the 1930s. In the beginning,
self-management was seen as a
transfer of the management role to
the economic collectives, that is,
companies. The reforms of the
sixties brought about a change in
ownership relations, state property
became social property and thus the
central, state-owned investment fund
was abolished. With it went the
system of central planning, too. The
power to decide on investments was
conferred, at least nominally, on
the companies which themselves –
albeit in the name of society – were
owned by the workers employed in
them. Finally, and probably most
importantly, normal trade and
financial relations with the world
were established, mediated by
commercial banks. This, in turn,
necessitated conducting the usual
monetary and fiscal policy.
The final motivation, however, was
that the next reform and future
economic and political adaptations
would lead to privatization and
democratization. And truly, with
certain constitutional solutions and
changes to the electoral system from
the beginning of the sixties, it
seemed as if things were starting to
move in that direction. To this one
should add the opening up of borders
and an increase in international
cooperation. All these systemic
changes had a temporary character
and the next changes were to involve
privatization and democratization.
At least, this is how things looked
in the mid-sixties.
The reforms turned out to be a
political failure. Their
continuation was abandoned, while
political changes took a completely
different, if not unexpected,
course. Privatization was stopped by
the student protests of 1968, while
democratization was halted by
nationalist movements that
threatened to bring about the
break-up of the country, also
occurring in 1968. The result was
that the majority of economic
changes were kept, although later
certain elements of the economic
system were modified so as to
harmonize with the political
changes. The latter, on the other
hand, went mainly in the direction
of strengthening the republics and
provinces at the expense of the
federation. Of key importance here
were the changes to the banking
system and the system of public
finances. In a sense,
nationalization (by the republics
and provinces – trans.) of assets
and taxpayers came about.
The research, both
foreign and domestic, most
frequently focused on the wrong
issues. Foreign economic research,
which was extensive, focused with
special intensity on the performance
of self-management companies and
their drawbacks that were to be
expected if one started out from the
assumptions of economic theory. On
the other hand, domestic studies
were devoted to the country’s
downgrading mostly from the legal or
constitutional aspects, as well as
to the shortcomings of a
decentralized socialist system in
which it was not possible to control
wages or investments from a center,
since the federation lacked above
all the fiscal, but also political
instruments necessary.
Of crucial importance, however, was
the relinquishing of further
democratization, which came about in
order to preserve stability – and
was achieved by a return to
authoritarianism and by a
redistribution of national
competencies. A debate similar to
the one conducted in the first
Yugoslavia, above all after the
territorial reorganization of 1939,
was renewed. This turnabout also
determined the political disputes
and their solutions which ultimately
led to the break-up of the country.
How did a system created to stop
economic reforms function? During
the 1970s, monetary policy was
mainly used to make sure that the
economy did business with a negative
real interest rate. This was a key
macroeconomic fact. As the federal
government had very limited powers
in the domain of fiscal policy,
monetary policy was the most
important instrument of overall
economic policy. Details are not of
paramount importance; it is
sufficient to point out that
interest rates were lower than the
rate of inflation in conditions of
what was practically a fixed rate of
exchange. As a consequence, this led
to an increase of investment and
spending, financed by foreign loans
and a growth in imports. As money
was cheap globally in the seventies,
this kind of economic policy was not
at odds with what was going on, not
only in the developed countries of
the world, but in some socialist
countries as well. Yugoslavia
probably fared better than most
because its foreign debt was to a
large degree funneled into
investments, while in other
socialist countries, for example the
Soviet Union, it was directed
towards spending (on wheat imports,
for example). Nevertheless, a great
disparity in the trade balance
developed, while foreign debt
accumulated. All the way up to the
economic crash of the eighties.
The economic system created in the
mid-sixties was supposed to increase
the efficiency of investments and
spur competitiveness on foreign
markets. The sum of reform measures
undertaken then were not that
different from those undertaken by
countries at the time of abandoning
socialism at the end of the eighties
and beginning of the nineties. The
regime of the foreign exchange rate
was balanced out, central banks were
empowered to deal with inflation,
while the fiscal system was meant to
secure the sustainability of public
finances. Finally, commercial banks
were established that took deposits
in hard currency and gradually
became capable of taking out foreign
loans and financing the investments
of domestic companies. Direct
foreign investments were not
possible, and neither were private
domestic investments - shortcomings
that were intended to be eliminated
at a later date. The system thus
established was capable of recycling
foreign assets, as well as of
monetary subsidies to the economy –
which in fact it did do once further
reforms were relinquished. So the
system that was established to
increase the efficiency of the
economy was ultimately used to
sustain self-management companies,
national budgets and buying
stability by increasing spending.
The seventies were the time when
this system produced favorable
results. Much research sees this
period – and the short period of
Ante Markovic’s government in 1990 –
as the golden age of Yugoslavia. The
dinar was strong, imported goods
were accessible, investments raised
the economy’s capacities, and in the
infrastructure was partially renewed
or enlarged. Remittances from abroad
also made a certain contribution
since in the sixties a great number
of workers had emigrated to Germany
and other countries that enjoyed
faster growth than there was
available work force. Thus a
macroeconomic system was established
that in certain elements persisted
mainly in Serbia up until the crisis
of 2008-2009.
Foreign Trade
Judging by the data of the Yugoslav
National Bank, the balance of trade
in the first Yugoslavia was on the
whole equalized. The economy was
pretty closed, measured by the ratio
of imports to exports and domestic
production. It was a matter of some
ten percent, that is, around twenty
if overall foreign exchange was
taken into account. In part this was
a consequence of the economic trends
immediately after World War I, when
inflation was a problem throughout
Europe, and then came the Great
Depression when foreign trade was
reduced everywhere. In later years,
the state attempted to utilize
protection measures, which curtailed
imports, but also exports since
there would occasionally be a ban on
exporting agricultural goods, which
was the most important export
commodity.
In the second Yugoslavia, financing
from abroad played a significant
role and thus imports were on the
whole greater than exports. Still,
the trade deficit began to be
significant only after the economic
reforms of the sixties, and became
particularly so after the political
stabilization at the beginning of
the seventies. Apart from the
policies of the exchange rate
(relatively stable) and of prices
(accelerated inflation), a
significant role was played by
increasing remittances from abroad.
Also, in the second half of the
seventies especially, loans taken
abroad also played a significant
role. By the end of the seventies,
exports covered imports by about 50
percent. The balance of services was
positive due to transit revenues, as
well as growing tourism, so that, if
remittances from workers abroad are
taken into account, the current
account of the balance of payments
showed a lesser deficit. This
characteristic will endure in the
majority of the newly- independent
states, at least until the crisis of
2008-2009.
Table 5
Trade flows
in the Socialist Federal Republic of
Yugoslavia1
Placement
on the local market, in % GDP
Placement
in other regions, in % GDP
Export,
in % GDP
Note: -
1) Includes end products and
intermediates.
Source:
OECD.
Table 5 contains data on domestic
and foreign trade. As can be seen,
the domestic market was certainly
much more important than the foreign
market, a characteristic which will
again persist even after the
break-up of the country, albeit not
in Slovenia, while things begin to
change under the influence of the
crisis of the eighties. The role of
this crisis is also visible in Table
5.
Table 6
Trade in
Southeast Europe (1980-1985)
Notes:
1) West Germany. – 2) SEE-1
(Southeast Europe - 1) Includes
Bulgaria, Hungary, Romania, and
Yugoslavia. – 3) SEE-2 (Southeast
Europe - 2) Includes SEE-1 with
Greece and Turkey.
Source:
The Vienna Institute
forIinternational Economic Studies
Right after the outbreak of the
crisis at the beginning of the
eighties, exports show a significant
growth in relation to GDP. Moreover,
this whole decade will show a much
more equalized trade balance than
the previous decade. The overall
picture becomes even better if we
add the export of services, which
became very significant with the
development of tourism. Generally
speaking, if overall foreign
exchange is taken into account,
Yugoslavia in the period after the
economic reforms (of the 1960s) was
trade-wise a significantly more open
country than the majority of the
successor states after the break-up,
but before the crisis of 2008-2009.
Table 7
Trade in
Southeast Europe (1990.)
Notes:
1) Including West and East Germany.
– 2) SEE-1 (Southeast Europe - 1)
Includes Bulgaria, Hungary, Romania,
and Yugoslavia. – 3) SEE-2
(Southeast Europe - 2) Includes
SEE-1 with Greece and Turkey.
Source:
The Vienna Institute for
International Economic Studies
It is also interesting to note the
change in trade partners during the
crisis of the 1980s. Tables 6 and 7
contain some comparative data. The
second half of the eighties sees a
significant increase of exports to
Germany and Italy, which will go on
to become the most significant trade
partners of the newly-emerged
independent states as well. Imports
from these two countries were
already significant earlier. In any
case, Yugoslavia had an increasingly
open economy in the period after the
economic reforms of the sixties.
The Lost Decade
The eighties were of key
significance not only for
Yugoslavia, but for the European
socialist world as a whole. If we
look at Images 1 and 2 it is clear
that this was a decade in which the
economy stagnated. From Tables 3 and
4 it can be seen that certain
republics fared better than others,
especially where employment was
concerned. But in terms of economic
growth there is practically little
difference between the regions. The
case was similar with other
socialist countries, even though the
reasons were different. In some,
like Yugoslavia, the problem was
high foreign debt, while in others
it was the drop in prices of oil and
other raw materials.
Yugoslavia practically went bankrupt
in 1981-1982 because it was unable
to pay back its foreign debt. The
reason for this was that monetary
policy had changed in the United
States and there was a sudden jump
in interest rates. Given that at the
time the foreign trade deficit of
Yugoslavia was really huge, the
further financing of imports through
foreign loans was not sustainable
and thus it was necessary to
rebalance imports and exports.
Furthermore, it was necessary to
secure the refinancing of already
existing loans at much higher, and
from the position of the country’s
trade capabilities, unsustainable
interest rates. A reduction of the
foreign trade deficit required a
significant correction to the dinar
exchange rate, while financing of
debt called for finding new sources
of revenue. The country, however,
could not adapt quickly enough and
actually never managed to fully
adapt all the way up to its very
break- up. Why?
The reason was of a systemic nature.
Here it is necessary to bear in mind
three key characteristics.
The first was the dispute over the
dinar exchange rate. Devaluation
would redistribute expenditures
among the republics. The issue of
hard currency earnings from tourism
was particularly sensitive. The
export sector, especially tourism,
would certainly gain from
devaluation, while sellers on the
domestic market would be worse off.
There was no mechanism of
compensation, mainly because the
fiscal system had changed
significantly in the meantime so
that the federal budget no longer
had the necessary means to
compensate those who fared worse
from revenue achieved by taxing
those who fared better. The central
bank used the hard currency rate of
exchange and selective lines of
credit to compensate, but this only
increased the disputes because the
terms were inequitable in a matter
that should have been equitable. In
fact, in this way the central bank
incurred obligations that could then
easily be turned into losses and
thus into fiscal expenditure for the
republics and provinces.
The second characteristic was the
expectation that credit would be
worth less when it became payable
because a negative interest rate
would be ascribed to it. In
conditions of loss of value of the
exchange rate, it would have been
necessary for inflation not to
compensate corrections to the
nominal exchange rate. This would
have, however, required a
significant change in the behavior
of companies, which, in turn, did
not show a willingness to sacrifice
implicit subvention through
accelerated inflation. And so the
entire decade was marked by losses
in the exchange rate and a parallel
acceleration of inflation. The
correction of the trade deficit was
more a consequence of the inability
to finance it and less a result of
exchange rate and monetary policies.
The third characteristic is probably
the most important. As a consequence
of social and national resistance to
economic reforms, one was precluded
from selling property as a means to
finance foreign debt. At the
beginning of the crisis in
1981-1982, foreign debt made up less
than a third of the overall Yugoslav
product. Interest rate obligations
were not small, but they in no way
exceeded several percentage points
of the domestic product. It would
have been relatively easy to turn
the debt into foreign investment if
companies had been allowed to issue
shares so as to secure the necessary
financing. This was not feasible
because of the ownership system
which precluded the sale of
property, especially to foreigners,
but also to private individuals in
general, and because it could also
lead to the spilling-over of
obligations and profits across the
borders of republics and provinces,
which was politically very hard to
swallow. It was not until 1988 that
agreement was reached with the
International Monetary Fund about
solidarity in sharing responsibility
for the foreign debt of the country.
These obstacles to a relatively
quick solution to the problem of
foreign debt made it very difficult
to start up economic production in
improved macroeconomic conditions,
which ultimately resulted in the
economy stagnating for a whole
decade with the constant
acceleration of inflation and growth
of the unemployment rate. Only at
the end of 1989 the government of
Ante Marković embarked on changing
these systemic characteristics,
which in the short term led to
improved economic trends in 1990,
but also to a renewed economic
crisis at the end of that year and
finally to the break-up of the
country in 1991.
During that entire decade, the
advocates of liberal economic
solutions and democratic political
legitimacy could not garner public
support for the necessary changes
while, at the same time, the
influence of the nationalists grew
until they finally prevailed in
Serbia, after which the break-up of
the country was inevitable. The more
developed republics repeatedly
highlighted the inequity of the
fiscal system, which was the alleged
cause of the overspill of their
assets to less developed regions,
while in Serbia the interest in new
territorial delimitation along
ethnic lines prevailed. While fiscal
problems were solvable, territorial
delineation along ethnic lines
naturally signified the end of the
common state.
Breakdown and Setback
Practically from the very inception
of the common state, the
distribution of gains and
expenditures between its constituent
parts was the key topic of debate
and dispute. The constitutional
framework was never accepted by
certain national (ethnic)
communities and in certain places
local control of the territory was
disputed. In the economic domain,
the fiscal system was deemed
inequitable by practically all
sides. In the end, the country broke
apart over the dispute of who was
paying how much into the common
coffer. This, of course, was just
the rationalization. However, this
dispute was to be expected given
that the diminishment of fiscal
powers by the federal government had
been a key demand from 1968 up to
the break- up itself. There was thus
first a fiscal devolution, which was
thoroughgoing and practically
complete, and then the Fund for the
Underdeveloped, which was
practically the only remaining
fiscal instrument for the
reallocation of assets, became the
focus of disputes, and then finally
even the central bank, which
intervened with selective credits
thus causing different regional
consequences, became a contentious
issue.
What was the specific problem with
the Central Bank and the banking
system as a whole? In the period of
adaptation to the crisis of foreign
debt during the eighties, the
financial picture changed in such a
way that the developed republics had
a trade surplus in exchange with the
less developed republics and the
province of Kosovo. In other words,
the country had divided itself into
creditor and debtor republics. The
financial significance of Slovenia
grew markedly. In part this was a
consequence of the Fund for the
Underdeveloped, even though it was
precisely the more developed
republics, above all Croatia and
Slovenia, which sought its
abolishment. However, to the degree
that money really moved from, let’s
say, Slovenia to Macedonia, goods
followed the money, too. So the
republics that had paid more money
into the Fund for the Underdeveloped
and then left it were also the
republics who sold more of their
goods to the less developed
republics and the province of
Kosovo. This was simply the domestic
balance of payments: that domestic
trade was financed by credits from
the more developed republics,
turning them into creditor
republics, while the lesser
developed regions became the
debtors. Because of this financial
asymmetry, measures that would in
one way or another assist the
financial recovery of the debtors
were not acceptable to the creditor
republics. But if the balance of
power at the level of the federal
government had changed, that could
have become feasible.
In this context, the rise of
nationalism in Serbia was of special
concern. The motives of the Serbian
nationalists were neither economic
nor predominantly financial (apart
from personal interest, of course).
Instead, they sought a change in the
balance of power at the federal
level with the objective of revising
the existing constitution and making
possible territorial corrections.
And truly, the Serbian nationalist
movement was a combination of
anti-liberal social demands from
1968 and nationalist territorial
demands above all towards the
provinces (Vojvodina and Kosovo –
trans.), but implicitly also towards
other regions (in other republics)
populated by Serbs (so-called
‘Serbian lands’ – trans.). These
political objectives brought about
the break-up of the country. But the
country never functioned well
economically either, and the
necessary reforms were not in
harmony with any of the Yugoslav
actors’ nationalist interests.
Costs of the Break Up
The nineties were economically bad
for all the states that emerged out
of Yugoslavia except for Slovenia.
There was a disruption of trade
ties, except for those within the
rump Yugoslavia (Serbia and
Montenegro – trans.), and between
Bosnia-Herzegovina and neighboring
Serbia and Croatia, but the scope of
that exchange was significantly less
than before the break-up and the
wars. Table 3 shows the difference
of the real per capita income in
relation to the income that would
have been achieved had long-term
relations with the Slovenian economy
been maintained. So that during the
nineties all other emerging Yugoslav
countries started lagging
significantly behind Slovenia, but
also behind other European
countries. From Image 2 it can be
seen that in practically all the
newly-emerged Yugoslav states the
level of the per capita income at
the beginning of the second decade
of the 21st century was on a par
with the level achieved during the
seventies or eighties (given that
the eighties were marked by
stagnation). In other words., the
countries in question had lost about
three decades of development. If we
take into account that the bigger
countries – Croatia, Serbia,
Bosnia-Herzegovina – did not achieve
visible growth in the period from
2008 until today, then we can even
talk about four decades of
stagnation. Only Slovenia had
positive growth, even though by
certain indicators, today it too is
further away from the European
developed countries than it was at
the end of the seventies or the end
of the eighties.
All in all, it is difficult to talk
about the economic benefits of
leaving Yugoslavia. Furthermore, if
one is to compare tax burdens,
especially bearing in mind the gains
of such tax expenditures, and
putting aside defense spending,
which in the second Yugoslavia was
considerable and today is much
reduced, it is difficult to claim
that the newly-emerged states are
less of a burden to the taxpayers
and the economy. It neither runs
counter to logic nor simple fact
that smaller states pose a greater
burden on taxpayers (with the
exception of micro-states, but only
Montenegro qualifies as such),
simply for reasons of the economy of
scope.
Finally, in terms of democratization
and liberalization, the
newly-independent states, with the
exception of Slovenia, are more
restricted than Yugoslavia, or at
least this has only started to
change very recently.
Democratization is incomplete and a
few of the newly-emerged states are
going through a constitutional
limbo. Slovenia and Croatia have
become European Union members, a
fact that has a stabilizing effect
on the economy and on political
relations, but the rest of the
former Yugoslavia has not achieved a
more durable stabilization of the
democratic system of
decision-making.
Regional Cooperation
After the war in Bosnia-Herzegovina
and particularly after the war in
Kosovo, the international community,
especially the United States and the
European Union, formulated a policy
of regional cooperation with the
idea that increased economic
cooperation would bring about
political stabilization and
normalization. The European Union
has invested substantial effort in
mobilizing interest in regional
cooperation principally among the
former Yugoslav states. Probably the
most important such regional project
is the regional free trade zone
known as CEFTA. It was established
in 2006 after existing bilateral
agreements on free trade developed
into a regional agreement. The
European Union additionally
supported this project by first
removing customs barriers on imports
from the Yugoslav countries, and
then concluding with them Agreements
on Stabilization and Association
which would ultimately lead to
European Union membership. With
CEFTA and free trade with the
European Union, liberalization
finally prevailed in the
newly-emerged Yugoslav states.
What is the possible contribution of
liberalization to economic
development? This is particularly
interesting because the crisis that
took hold of the Yugoslav states
from 2008 up to the present has a
lot in common with the crisis from
the beginning of the eighties. In
the same way, the period that
preceded the crisis has much in
common with the period from the
seventies. Thus these two distinct
crisis periods and their
consequences are comparable.
Development after 2000, which
represents a kind of new beginning
for the entire region since both
(Croatian strongman) Franjo Tudjman
and (Serbian strongman) Slobodan
Milošević exited the political
stage, has the same characteristics
of uneven progress as the period of
the seventies. Trade deficits
increase, foreign debt becomes
greater, and unemployment has not
been reduced to an acceptable
level.. The last is noteworthy among
other things because many
explanations for the growth of
unemployment in Yugoslavia after the
economic reforms (of the sixties)
can be understood differently today.
Back then explanations saw the
growth of unemployment as caused by
institutional factors, especially by
the system of self-management.
Namely, employees as owners have an
interest in increasing investments
and not increasing the number of
employed because that way they
increase their own income, which
apart from their salary also
partakes in the company profits..
This should explain the growth of
capital in relation to labor and the
limited mobility of the labor force.
Nevertheless, when one looks at
development in the majority of
European post-socialist or
transition countries, one notices
that the tendency for economic
growth to be based on growth in
productivity and not growth in
employment, is present everywhere.
This makes sense if the development
in question is financed by foreign
assets, as was to a large degree the
case in Yugoslavia after the
economic reforms because investments
will be turned into the most
productive technology, due to which,
again, employment will grow at a
slower rate, particularly if it is a
question of those employed in the
state sector being pre-qualified for
work in the new industries or the
services sector. So that in
transition economies, and such at
the outset was the Yugoslav economy
after economic reforms, productivity
takes precedence over employment.
This to a large degree also occurred
in the emerging Yugoslav states in
the first decade of the 21st
century. Growth was mainly based on
productivity, while employment even
showed a tendency to shrink.
Therefore the problem lay not in
unemployment, but rather in the
economic sectors in which
investments were directed. During
the seventies, Yugoslavia invested
in industry, but not an
insignificant part of the foreign
debt went into spending.
Additionally, efficiency was a
problem due to negative interest
rate subsidies. By contrast, most
emerging Yugoslav states, except for
Croatia and Montenegro, made use of
the post-2000 period of low interest
rates mainly to invest in non-export
services. As a result, by and large
foreign debt was directed into the
production of non-exchangeable goods
and into spending. Ultimately, all
the former Yugoslav countries faced
the financial crisis of 2008 with
high foreign debt. Just as at
beginning of the eighties, the
refinancing of these debts was made
difficult, not so much by the higher
cost of loans, but by the need for
foreign creditors to put their own
finances into order. And so the
entire region found itself in a
similar situation to the one from
the 1980s, with the difference that
there was now little leftover
property, the sale of which would
help cover the debts. Thus it was
necessary to correct the exchange
rate where it was overvalued, or cut
spending, by reducing employment if
there was no other way, leading to a
leveling-out of the current balance
of payments with greater exports and
reduced imports. This is a process
that has been underway for almost a
decade in the new Yugoslav states,
which, time-wise, is similar to the
eighties.
Here it is important only to see
what the role of a more liberal
trade framework is in relation to
the one from the 1980s. The
existence of a regional free trade
zone was certainly helpful, for it
preserved the level of trade
inherited from the period prior to
2008. However, access to the market
of the European Union had
significantly more impact. In the
period from 2008 to 2016, all the
new Yugoslav countries increased
their exports from 30 to 60 percent,
with imports stagnating at a level
close to that of 2008. The advantage
of liberalization today in relation
to resistance against it during the
eighties certainly influenced
adaptability to the crisis. Even
though the key problems - foreign
trade deficits and foreign debt -
are the same.
However, it is worth pointing out
that, irrespective of the above, the
European Union is increasingly
unpopular, that nationalism is on
the rise, and that regional
cooperation has occurred in spite
of, and not as a consequence of, the
policies of the new Yugoslav states.
Conclusion
Yugoslavia did not succeed in
achieving liberalization and
democratization, but it was not an
obstacle to them either since the
newly-emerging states after its
dissolution have not displayed a
durable affinity for liberal
measures or sustainable democracy,
nor, for that matter, for regional
cooperation either. However,
circumstances have changed and so
far nationalist and authoritarian
forces have not prevailed as they
did when they dissolved the joint
state. The economic cost of
non-liberal and nationalist politics
is permanent backwardness due to
their unsustainability in conditions
of modern development.
Literature
Bicanic, R, Ekonomska podloga
hrvatskog pitanja (The Economic
Basis of the Croatian National
Issue). Zagreb, 2004 (first edition
1933).
Gligorov, V, Why Do Countries Break
Up? The Case of Yugoslavia. Uppsala,
1994.
Gligorov, V, „Elusive Development in
the Balkans: Research Findings“,
wiiw Policy Notes and Reports 2016
(wiiw - Wiener Institut für
Internationale
Wirtschaftsvergleiche; Vienna
Institute for International Economic
Studies).
Lampe, J. R, Yugoslavia as History.
Cambridge University Press, 1996.
Palairet, M, Balkan Economies c.
1980-1914: Evolution without
Development. Cambridge University
Press, 1997.
|